Show pageOld revisionsBacklinksBack to top This page is read only. You can view the source, but not change it. Ask your administrator if you think this is wrong. ====== Jean-Baptiste Say ====== Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832) was a French classical economist and businessman who championed free markets and left an indelible mark on economic thought. While a contemporary and admirer of [[Adam Smith]], Say was a significant thinker in his own right, best known for a principle so famous it bears his name: [[Say's Law]]. In its simplest form, this law is often summarized as "supply creates its own demand." The core idea is that the very act of producing goods and services generates the income (in the form of wages, profits, and rent) necessary to purchase those goods and services. For Say, economic prosperity isn't born from consuming more, but from producing more. He saw money as a mere facilitator of exchange; ultimately, people trade the goods they produce for the goods others produce. This production-first perspective offers a powerful, if controversial, lens through which to view economies and investments. ===== Who Was Jean-Baptiste Say? ===== Born in Lyon, France, Say lived through the tumult of the French Revolution and the Napoleonic era. His practical experience as the owner of a cotton mill deeply informed his economic theories. His magnum opus, *A Treatise on Political Economy* (1803), was a runaway success across Europe and America, becoming a standard economics textbook for much of the 19th century. Thomas Jefferson so admired the book that he tried to persuade Say to become a professor at the newly founded University of Virginia. Say's work is celebrated for its clarity and its sharp focus on the real-world application of economic principles, particularly his emphasis on the critical role of the //entrepreneur// as the engine of economic progress. ===== Say's Law: Supply Creates Its Own Demand ===== ==== The Core Idea ==== Imagine a self-sufficient farmer. He grows wheat (supply). He can either eat the wheat himself (demand) or trade his surplus wheat with a shoemaker for a new pair of shoes. His production of wheat directly creates his ability to demand shoes. Now, expand this to an entire economy. When a company builds a factory to produce cars, it doesn't just create a supply of cars. It also creates demand by: * Paying wages to its workers. * Buying raw materials from its suppliers. * Generating profits for its owners and shareholders. The total value of the income distributed is, by definition, equal to the total value of the cars produced. This combined income is then used to buy those cars and other products. In this view, a general "glut" of unsold goods across the entire economy is impossible because the act of supplying goods simultaneously creates the purchasing power to demand them. ==== Misconceptions and Nuances ==== Say's Law is often misunderstood. It does //not// mean that anything you produce will magically find a buyer. Say was well aware that a company could misjudge the market and produce too many purple hats when consumers wanted green ones. This would lead to a glut of purple hats and a shortage of green ones. However, he argued this was a problem of //misallocated production//, not a general failure of demand. The solution wasn't for the government to stimulate "demand" but for entrepreneurs to stop making unwanted products and shift resources toward producing things people actually desire. The problem isn't a lack of purchasing power in the system; it's that the purchasing power is directed elsewhere. ===== Relevance for Value Investors ===== While Say's Law is a macroeconomic principle, its underlying philosophy resonates deeply with the core tenets of [[value investing]]. ==== Focus on Productive Value ==== Value investors seek to buy businesses, not just trade stocks. Say's emphasis on production aligns perfectly with this. A company's long-term worth comes from its ability to efficiently create goods or services that customers want, not from financial gimmickry or short-term, debt-fueled demand spikes. When analyzing a business, a Say-influenced investor asks: "Does this company create real, sustainable value through its operations?" This is a far more important question than "Will the government's next stimulus package boost its quarterly sales?" ==== A Long-Term, Self-Correcting View ==== Say's Law promotes a long-term perspective. It suggests that free-market economies, while prone to temporary disruptions and [[business cycles]], are inherently self-correcting. This encourages the patience central to value investing. Instead of panicking during a downturn, a value investor with this mindset sees an opportunity. They trust that if a company remains fundamentally productive, the market will eventually recognize its value, as temporary gluts and recessions give way to rational reallocation of resources. ==== A Healthy Skepticism of Demand-Side Fixes ==== Say's ideas stand in stark contrast to [[Keynesian Economics]], championed by [[John Maynard Keynes]], which argues that aggregate demand can be insufficient and that government spending is needed to cure recessions. Modern economic policy is heavily influenced by Keynes. For a value investor, understanding Say provides a crucial counterpoint. It fosters a healthy skepticism toward companies that are overly dependent on government contracts or stimulus-driven consumption. The most resilient businesses are those that thrive by meeting genuine market needs, not by riding the coattails of government spending.